The involvement of board of directors and institutional

Journal of International Management
4 (1998) 337–351
The involvement of board of directors and institutional
investors in investing in transition economies:
An agency theory approach
Laszlo Tihanyi a,*, Alan E. Ellstrand b
a
Department of Management, School of Business Administration and Economics,
California State University, Fullerton, CA 92834, USA
b
Department of Management and Human Resource Management, College of Business Administration,
California State University, Long Beach, CA 90840, USA
Abstract
We investigate the influence of the composition of the board of directors and stock ownership patterns on the decision to enter markets in Central and Eastern Europe. Our findings suggest that board
composition alone does not influence the entry decision while firms with less concentrated stock ownership were more likely to enter these developing markets. We also found that while better performing
firms were attracted to opportunities in Central and Eastern Europe, firms with poor prior performance
and outside dominated boards were also more likely to enter these markets. © 1999 Elsevier Science
Inc. All rights reserved.
Keywords: Corporate governance; Central and Eastern Europe; Transition economies; Board of directors
Using an agency theory perspective, we investigate the influence of key corporate governance mechanisms on the decision to enter markets of Central and Eastern Europe. We suggest a series of hypotheses to explore the relationship between the composition of the board
of directors, the level of institutional stock ownership and management’s decision to invest
in the transition econonmies of Central and Eastern Europe. Our sample consisted of 133
firms selected at random from the 1991 Fortune 500. We used binary logit analysis to analyze our data.
Our findings suggest that board composition alone does not influence the decision to enter
the markets in Central and Eastern Europe. However, we found that poorly performing firms
with outsider-dominated boards were more likely to enter the Central and Eastern European
markets. In addition, our results suggest that firms with less concentrated stock ownership
* Corresponding author. Tel: 714-278-4555; Fax: 714-278-2645; E-mail: [email protected].
1075-4253/98/$–see front matter © 1999 Elsevier Science Inc. All rights reserved.
PII: S1075-4253(98)00019-2
338
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
also were more likely to enter these developing markets. Our results provide some support
for the agency theory perspective in this international context. We offer suggestions for further research in this area.
1. Introduction
The opportunities and risks associated with international expansion have been of interest
to researchers in international business (Rugman, 1981; Hennart, 1982; Grant, 1987; Dunning 1988; McKiernan 1992; Mitchell et al., 1992; Caves 1996). Numerous studies have
found that investments in developing countries are associated with greater levels of uncertainty (e.g., Root and Ahmed, 1978; Sabi, 1988; Collins, 1990). Since the late 1980s, the developing countries of Central and Eastern Europe have been making the transition from centrally planned to market economies. This has created numerous opportunities for businesses
interested in investing in the region (Lavigne, 1995; Lyles and Salk, 1996; Brouthers and Bamossy, 1997; De Castro and Uhlenbruck, 1997). However, the expansion into these newly
developing markets has often been accompanied by significant risks to multinational firms
(Collins and Rodrik, 1991; Welfens, 1992; Froot, 1994).
The potential for success or failure resulting from expansion into the highly volatile environments of transition economies may generate interest and possibly conflict among key
stakeholders of the firm. The agency theory perspective has been found to be an appropriate
framework to examine the possible effects of various stakeholder groups on important strategic decisions (e.g, Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Fama and Jensen, 1983; Eisenhardt, 1989).
Agency theory has been applied to study various research issues in the international management field, such as international trade (Mirus and Yeung, 1986), international joint ventures
(Reuer and Miller, 1997), international franchise operations (Fladmoe-Lindquist and Jacque,
1995), and foreign subsidiary management (Roth and O’Donnell, 1996). However, little research has focused on the agency problem associated with firm internationalization. The purpose of this article is to examine the influence of key governance mechanisms such as boards
of directors and institutional investors on international expansion into the transition economies of Central and Eastern Europe.
2. Background and hypothesis development
When considering expansion into new international markets, firms are seeking opportunities that may lead to enhanced profitability and growth (Dunning, 1988; Loree and Guisinger, 1995; Caves, 1996). However, empirical research regarding the results of international
expansion has provided mixed results. Michel and Shaked (1986) found higher performance
for domestic firms than for multinational firms. Collins (1990) reported that multinational
firms with developing country operations had lower performance than domestic firms and
multinationals with developed country operations. However, this study did not find performance differences between the last two groups. By contrast, studies by Hughes et al. (1975)
and Kim et al. (1993) found that multinational corporations had higher performance than domestic firms. Geringer et al. (1989) identified a curvilinear relationship between international
expansion and firm performance. These researchers suggest that this relationship may be due
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
339
to escalating costs related to geographic dispersion. A recent study by Hitt et al. (1997) found
support for the findings of Geringer et al. (1989). These researchers argue that the eventual
performance decline may be due to the increased complexity of international operations.
Because of the potential opportunities and threats associated with international expansion,
managers must consider several factors before committing resources to enter new markets.
For example, developing markets may provide a source of low-cost labor and large numbers
of consumers whose needs may not be met by existing businesses. Thus, these markets may
provide attractive opportunities for any firm willing to face the risks associated with entering
these markets. Nevertheless, the risks associated with entering developing markets also may
be significant as these markets may be politically and economically unstable, with high currency exchange risk, high inflation, and inadequate infrastructure for business development
(Root and Ahmed, 1978; Sabi, 1988).
The political events of the late 1980s lead to significant reforms in the economies of the
Central and Eastern European nations. These nations had operated as centrally planned economies with governments establishing price and production levels after World War II (Gomulka,
1986; Bergson, 1989; Kornai, 1992). With the political and economic changes of the late 1980s,
nations in Central and Eastern Europe began the transition to market-based economic systems (Kornai, 1990; Blanchard et al., 1991; Montias, 1992; Antal-Mokos, 1998). While local
citizens as well as outside interests initially received the reforms with much hope and enthusiasm, the transition has proven to be a complicated process for many countries in the region
(Olson, 1992; Portes, 1993). Whereas some countries have been relatively successful at introducing the economic reforms necessary to establish consumer markets, other nations have encountered significant resistance to installing market reforms. The short-term outcome of the
transition is a diverse group of countries with differing political views, government policies
and varying levels of economic development (Welfens, 1992; Marer, 1993; Lavigne, 1995).
Multinational firms entering Central and Eastern Europe have found that the experience has
not always met expectations. A study on initial attitudes toward investing in the transition
economies of Eastern Europe by Collins and Rodrik (1991) found that multinational companies focused primarily on beating their competitors and being first entrants in the region’s
markets. However, multinational companies have gradually reduced their expectations due to
the difficulties they have encountered in establishing local operations and the uncertain status and direction of government economic transformation programs (Froot, 1994). De Castro
and Uhlenbruck (1997) suggest that difficulties associated with government regulation in
transition economies are more likely to include post-privatization requirements such as assurances of new investment, tax policies, and price controls, than in other developing countries.
While existing research has focused on motivations for entry into this region, our study
seeks to understand the role of the corporate governance process in approving entry into this
potentially rewarding but uncertain market. Specifically, we examine the influence of corporate governance mechanisms—board of directors’ composition and institutional stock ownership on entry into the Central and Eastern European market.
The board of directors is positioned at the top of the corporate governance structure of the
modern business corporation (Lorsch and MacIver, 1989). While the board serves many important governance functions, one of its key roles is that of providing oversight and control
over the decisions of top management (Zahra and Pearce, 1989; Pearce and Zahra, 1992). In
this control function, the board of directors is responsible for monitoring the strategic deci-
340
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
sions of top corporate executives including international expansion decisions. (Andrews,
1971; Demb et al., 1989).
In the modern business corporation, small corporate investors (owners) are far removed
from corporate decision makers. This separation of ownership and control may leave shareholders vulnerable to two agency problems (Fama and Jensen, 1983; Eisenhardt, 1989).
First, managers may have different goals for the corporation than shareholders. Managers
may be primarily concerned with reward maximization and job security while investors may
be seeking the highest possible returns. A second conflict may result from differing attitudes
toward risk. Because shareholders can diversify their investment portfolios they may be attracted to high-risk/high-return opportunities. However, managers may be reticent to pursue
high-risk projects due to the potential for failure, which creates employment risk for these
executives (Jensen and Meckling, 1976).
Agency theorists suggest that the board of directors is in place to monitor and interpret the
decisions of top managers and possibly intervene on behalf of shareholders. The composition
of the board of directors is a critical factor in establishing the effectiveness of the board as an
objective monitor of management (Fama and Jensen, 1983). Board composition refers to the
relative numbers of inside (management) and outside (nonmanagement) directors serving on
the board. Agency theorists suggest that boards dominated by inside directors may be less
vigilant monitors of management as these directors may intentionally provide self-serving
accounts of managerial actions to enhance their status with the firm’s chief executive officer
(Fama, 1980; Eisenhardt, 1989). By contrast, outside directors are thought to be vital in ensuring that an effective, impartial governance system is allowed to operate within the corporation since outside directors have more independence from management (Fama, 1980).
Johnson et al. (1993) suggest that outsider-dominated boards, because of their greater objectivity in evaluating firm performance, will be inclined to support higher risk but potentially more rewarding strategies. These boards may support internationalization decisions
that result in entry into the emerging markets of Central and Eastern Europe. The region includes a large number of consumers, a skilled but relatively low-cost labor force, and many
industrial centers, when compared with other developing countries. These opportunities have
attracted multinational companies to invest over $18 billion in Central and Eastern Europe
during the period 1990 to 1995. Emphasizing the opportunities available in Central and Eastern Europe, De Castro and Uhlenbruck (1997) note that these countries are less likely to impose restrictions on investments, such as local ownership and employment requirements,
than less-developed countries. This is may be due to the capital inflow and hard currency
needs of the governments of transition economies.
However, firms entering this region have found a great deal of economic and political instability in the wake of the major changes that transformed the region a decade ago. Corporate shareholders may not be concerned about these potential risk factors because they have
the opportunity to reduce risk through portfolio diversification. Thus, these shareholders may
favor companies that invest in these emerging markets based on their potential for significant
growth and increased profits. Outsider-dominated boards tend to support the interests of
shareholders over management. Therefore,
H1: Boards with a majority of outside directors will support strategies that lead to entry
into the markets of Central and Eastern Europe.
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
341
While the board of directors may be a necessary and effective mechanism for protecting
the interests of small investors, large institutional shareholders, who control more than onehalf of America’s corporate equity, may prefer to present their concerns directly to corporate
management (Salwen and Lublin, 1992.). While there are various theories on the level of activism among institutions, Kochhar and David (1996) identify large institutions that take a
long-term perspective in their investments as “superior investors” and “active investors.”
These investors may be unable to freely trade large blocks of corporate equity as such sales
may trigger concern in the investment community, leading to significant price declines (Coffee, 1991; Cox, 1993). As a result, these large institutions must carefully consider investments for opportunities that will provide significant long-term returns (Kochhar and David,
1996). These shareholders have the resources to employ analysts who monitor and evaluate
the actions of corporate management. As they gain stature in the corporate community, these
large, influential shareholders are insisting on a greater role in the governance of corporations (Oviatt, 1988).
Because of their “illiquidity” problem these institutional investors may look for and even
encourage investments by firms that will lead to higher returns over the long term while also
increasing the level of risk (Johnson and Millon, 1993; Kochhar and David, 1996). Therefore, entry into the emerging markets of Central and Eastern Europe may present an attractive long-term strategic opportunity for institutional equity managers. As a result,
H2: Corporations whose equity is held in the majority by large, institutional shareholders will be more likely to enter the markets of Central and Eastern Europe.
As previously discussed, there is substantial empirical evidence to suggest that internationalization affects firm performance (e.g., Michel and Shaked, 1986; Geringer et al., 1989;
Dunning, 1993; Caves, 1996; Hitt et al., 1997). However, little is known about the influence
of prior performance on internationalization decisions. Empirical work in strategic management suggests that prior performance may have a significant influence on organizational actions (Whetten, 1987; Boeker and Goodstein, 1991). Studies have shown that better performing firms are more open to expansion and uncertainty (Child and Kieser, 1981; Dutton and
Duncan, 1987) and are more likely to increase their international involvement (Patterson et
al., 1997). Researchers also have found that poor performance increases rigidity and conservatism reducing the probability of organizational action (Staw et al., 1981; Singh, 1986).
Based on these findings, we expect that poor performing firms will be less likely to expand
into the transition economies of Central and Eastern Europe.
Researchers note, that when prior performance is poor, changes are more likely to be initiated by outsiders, rather than executives inside the company (Dalton and Kesner, 1985). Firms
reporting poor performance that have boards dominated by outside directors may be more
sensitive to the need to adopt bold policies that may lead to significant change including entry into new international markets (Johnson et al., 1993). By contrast, those firms reporting
higher levels of performance with boards dominated by insiders may take a more conservative approach.
The level of institutional stock ownership also may interact with prior firm performance to
significantly influence a firm’s strategic decisions. Firms reporting poor performance that
have high levels of institutional ownership may be pressured by these activist owners to
342
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
change the strategic direction of the firm to improve corporate performance. These firms
may be inclined to enter new markets to improve performance (Kochhar and David, 1996).
By contrast, those firms reflecting lower levels of performance with less concentrated equity
holdings may be more likely to avoid strategic change. Thus,
H3a: Firms reporting poor prior performance will be less likely to enter the Central and
Eastern European market.
H3b: Firms with poor prior performance and boards with a majority of outsiders will be
more likely to enact strategies that lead to entry into the markets of Central and Eastern
Europe than firms with poor performance and insiders dominated boards.
H3c: Firms with poor prior performance whose equity is held in the majority by large,
institutional shareholders will be more likely to support strategies that lead to entry into
the markets of Central and Eastern Europe than firms with poor performance and diffused ownership structure.
3. Methods
Our original sample included 150 firms selected at random from the Fortune 500 for
1991. From this sample of 150, we excluded those firms with existing investments in Central
and Eastern Europe prior to the initiation of the transition in 1989. In addition, firms with
missing governance data also were removed from our sample. As a result our final sample
consisted of 133 firms.
Data for our dependent variable, the firms’ investments in the transition economies of
Central and Eastern Europe, were collected from volumes of the Directory of American
Firms Operating in Foreign Countries from 1991 to 1996. The Directory includes listings of
overseas companies that have been identified by the parent firms as being a wholly or partially owned subsidiary, an affiliate, or a branch. Firms were coded “1” if they had made investment in the transition economies of Central and Eastern Europe, and “0” otherwise.
Countries in this study included the former communist countries of Central and Eastern Europe, including countries comprising the former Soviet Union, its satellites, and the former
Yugoslavia (Child and Czeglédy, 1996; De Castro and Uhlenbruck, 1997).
Institutional investors. Data on the firms’ ownership were coded as “1” if the ownership of
the firm was concentrated (when the majority of the stock was held by institutional investors)
and “0” in case of diffused ownership (when the majority of ownership was divided among
other equity holders). We chose to use a dichotomous measure in this case to capture the influence of majority institutional ownership. This information was gathered from the CD Disclosure database.
Board composition. Board composition was coded as “1” when the majority of board
members were outsiders (nonemployees) and “0” when the majority of the board members
were insiders. We selected a dichotomous measure for this variable as we wanted to capture
the decision-making influence associated with outside directors holding a voting majority on
the board. Data on board structure and stock ownership were collected from proxy statements.
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
343
3.1. Prior performance
The measurement of prior performance was based on the firms’ average return on investment (ROI) from 1988 to 1990. ROI was collected from the COMPUSTAT database. Using
the ROI data, we created three categories based on the distribution of the data: poor, fair, and
good performers. We chose to categorize performance into three equal groups as we hypothesized that governance agents including directors and institutional investors would assign
firm performance into general categories when making governance decisions.
4. Results
The descriptive statistics and correlations are reported in Table 1. Because of the binomial
distribution generated by our dependent variable, data analysis was completed by using binary logit analysis in SPSS Loglinear. The maximum likelihood estimation used in logit
analysis is concerned with selecting parameter estimates that imply the highest probability of
having obtained the observed sample dependent variable (Maddala, 1983; Aldrich and Nelson, 1984). The saturated model is presented in Table 2. This full model in SPSS Loglinear is
used to illustrate the variables whose parameters differ significantly from zero, that is, when
any of the partial Z-tests of a variable is significant (Norusis, 1990; Stevens, 1992). According to the Z-tests presented in Table 2, institutional investors, prior performance, and the interaction of prior performance and board structure are significant (p Ͻ 0.05), with the individual confidence intervals of significant parameters not covering zero.
The logit model presented in Table 3 includes only the significant effects. This more parsimonious logit model is specified as shown in Eq. (1):
log O invest = β int + β x i + β x j + β x
I I
P P
PB PB
(1)
jk .
where logOinvest is the log odds of investment in transition economies, ␤int is the intercept, ␤I,
␤P, and ␤PB are the parameter estimates for institutional investors (xIi), prior performance
(xPj), and the interactive effect of prior performance and board structure (x PBjk), respectively.
This model can be transformed into a logit model of event probability (e.g., Liao, 1994),
where Pinvest denotes the probability of investment in transition economies as shown in Eq. 2:
P invest = exp ( β int + β x i + β x j + β x
I I
P P
PB PB
jk )
( 1 + exp ( β int + β x i + β x j + β x
I I
P P
⁄
PB PB
jk ) ) .
(2)
Table 1
Descriptive statistics and correlations among the variables
Investment in transition economies
Institutional investors
Board of directors
Prior performance
* Significant at p Ͻ 0.05.
Mean
Standard
deviation
1
2
3
0.21
0.74
0.65
1.90
0.41
0.44
0.48
0.91
Ϫ0.194*
Ϫ0.081
0.076
0.130
0.030
Ϫ0.010
344
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
Table 2
Results of logit analysis
Intercept
Institutional investors
Diffused
Concentrated
Prior performance
Poor
Fair
Good
Board structure
Insider
Outsider
Prior performance*
Institutional investors
Poor
Diffused
Concentrated
Fair
Diffused
Concentrated
Good
Diffused
Concentrated
Institutional investors *
Board structure
Diffused
Insider
Outsider
Concentrated
Insider
Outsider
Prior performance*
Board structure
Poor
Insider
Outsider
Fair
Insider
Outsider
Good
Insider
Outsider
␤
exp(␤)
Z-tests
Ϫ0.946
0.388
Ϫ3.568*
0.546
Ϫ0.546
1.726
0.579
2.061*
Ϫ2.061*
Ϫ0.742
0.642
0.100
0.476
1.900
1.105
Ϫ1.960*
1.566
0.256
0.174
Ϫ0.174
1.190
0.840
0.652
Ϫ0.652
0.236
Ϫ0.236
1.266
0.790
0.623
Ϫ0.623
Ϫ0.240
0.240
0.787
1.271
Ϫ0.589
0.589
0.004
Ϫ0.004
1.004
0.996
0.010
Ϫ0.010
Ϫ0.028
0.028
0.972
1.028
Ϫ0.103
0.103
0.028
Ϫ0.028
1.028
0.972
0.103
Ϫ0.103
Ϫ0.974
0.974
0.378
2.649
Ϫ2.574*
2.574*
0.682
Ϫ0.682
1.978
0.506
1.669†
Ϫ1.669†
0.292
Ϫ0.292
1.339
0.747
0.749
Ϫ0.749
(continued on next page)
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
345
Table 2 (continued)
Prior performance*
Institutional investor*
Board structure
Poor
Diffused
Insider
Outsider
Concentrated
Insider
Outsider
Fair
Diffused
Insider
Outsider
Concentrated
Insider
Outsider
Good
Diffused
Insider
Outsider
Concentrated
Insider
Outsider
␤
exp(␤)
Z-tests
0.124
Ϫ0.124
1.132
0.883
0.327
Ϫ0.327
Ϫ0.124
0.124
0.883
1.132
Ϫ0.327
0.327
0.270
Ϫ0.270
1.310
0.763
0.662
Ϫ0.662
Ϫ0.270
0.270
0.763
1.310
Ϫ0.662
0.662
Ϫ0.394
0.394
0.674
1.483
Ϫ1.010
1.010
0.394
Ϫ0.394
1.483
0.674
1.010
Ϫ1.010
Saturated model. n ϭ 133.
* Significant at p Ͻ 0.05; † Significant at p Ͻ 0.10.
The analysis presented in Table 2 indicates that the individual effect of board structure was
not significant, thus hypothesis 1 was not supported. Results indicate a significant effect for
the variable institutional investors although the result was in the opposite direction suggested
by hypothesis 2. More specifically, the results of the final logit model indicate that for firms
with a majority of noninstitutional ownership the odds of investing in transition economies
are estimated to be 1.811 times higher than for firms with majority institution ownership, ceteris paribus.
According to our analysis, prior firm performance had a significant individual effect on
the dependent variable. Results show a decreased chance of investing in transition economies (0.344) for firms with poor prior performance when compared to other firms. For firms
with fair prior performance the odds of investing in transition economies are 2.363 higher
than for other firms. As a result, hypothesis 3a is supported.
Significant effects were found for the interaction term of prior performance and board
structure, providing support for hypothesis 3b. We found that firms with poor prior performance and insider board structure have decreased odds of investing in transition economies
(0.267) when compared to firms with similar performance but with different board structure.
For firms with poor performance and outsider boards the likelihood of investing in transition
346
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
Table 3
The effects of institutional investors, prior performance, and prior performance* board structure on investing in
transition economies
Intercept
Institutional investors
Diffused
Concentrated
Prior performance
Poor
Fair
Good
Prior performance* board structure
Poor
Insider
Outsider
Fair
Insider
Outsider
Good
Insider
Outsider
Goodness-of-fit statistics
Likelihood ratio chi-square
Pearson chi-square
Measures of association
Shannon’s entropy measure
Gini’s concentration measure
␤
exp(␤)
Z-tests
Ϫ1.168
0.311
Ϫ4.308*
0.594
Ϫ0.594
1.811
0.552
2.406*
Ϫ2.406*
Ϫ1.068
0.860
0.208
0.344
2.363
1.231
Ϫ2.524*
2.101*
0.507
Ϫ1.320
1.320
0.267
3.743
Ϫ2.858*
2.858*
0.810
Ϫ0.810
2.248
0.445
1.879†
Ϫ1.879†
0.510
Ϫ0.510
1.665
0.600
1.159
Ϫ1.159
df ϭ 6
df ϭ 6
p ϭ 0.649
p ϭ 0.677
4.203
3.995
0.137
0.140
n ϭ 133. Results are from the final logit model.
* Significant at p Ͻ 0.05; † Significant at p Ͻ 0.10.
economies is estimated to be 3.743 higher than for firms with poor performance but insider
board structure. The final model indicates a marginally significant effect for the parameter
estimates of the interaction of fair performance and board structure. However, we found no
significant effect for the interaction between prior performance and institutional investors,
thus hypothesis 3c was rejected.
The goodness-of-fit tests indicate that the final model fits the observed data well, with a
likelihood ratio chi-square of 4.203 (df ϭ 6; p ϭ 0.649). The concentration coefficient of the
final model is 0.14. This measure indicates the association between our dependent variable
and the independent variables in the final model (DeMaris, 1992). However, researchers suggest that the magnitude of this measure maybe small even when the variables are strongly related, therefore the magnitude should not be interpreted similarly to R2 in regression (Haberman, 1982; Aldrich and Nelson, 1984).
Tansey et al. (1996) recommended the use of multiple techniques when analyzing categorical data. We performed a logistic regression procedure as a secondary analysis to ensure the
robustness of our analysis. The results of the logistic regression validated our loglinear analysis. These results are presented in Table A1 in the Appendix.
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
347
5. Discussion
Using an agency theory perspective, we examined the relationship between board composition, ownership structure, and the strategic decision to enter the transition economies of
Central and Eastern Europe in the early 1990s. We also investigated the effects of firm performance in this situation. Our results indicate some support for our contention that these
governance variables have a significant influence on the decision to enter the transition economies.
We did not find a significant relationship between board composition and entry into the
transition economies of Central and Eastern Europe except when firm performance was considered. This may suggest that the decision to enter the transition economies in the early
1990s was a complex one that was not determined based on traditional attitudes toward risk
and reward. It is also possible that directors, regardless of background, were not directly involved in this decision. Rather, these directors may have deferred to the top management
team and simply approved their decision. Researchers should focus more attention on the
role of the board of directors in this situation to better understand the dynamics between the
board and top management in arriving at this important strategic decision.
Contrary to our hypothesis, we found that firms with lower levels of institutional ownership were more inclined to enter the Central and Eastern European markets. It is possible that
entry into the transitional economies may represent an unacceptable level of risk for institutional investors. The results may also suggest that the opportunities for long-term returns, as
suggested by Kochhar and David (1996), are viewed as uncertain in transition economies by
“active institutional investors.” Thus, institutions may discourage firms from entering this region. Clearly, more research should be conducted to better understand this relationship.
We found that firm performance did influence the decision to enter the transition economies of Central and Eastern Europe. Our findings suggest that middle range performers were
most likely to enter these emerging markets. This might indicate that firms may be reluctant
to engage in risk-taking behavior when performance is good. In addition, poor performers
may lack the resources or the necessary firm-specific advantages to engage in a major strategic initiative such as entering speculative new markets. Thus, the middle range performers
have both the motive and resources to enter these markets. This outcome is consistent with
previous work exploring motives concerning risk and returns in the strategic management literature (Fiegenbaum and Thomas, 1988).
While we did not find a significant interaction between firm performance and institutional
ownership, we did find a significant interaction between firm performance and board composition. As expected, when corporations are performing poorly, those firms with boards dominated by outsiders are more likely to accept the risk to invest in transitional economies. This
supports the position that outside directors become especially vigilant in representing shareholders interests only when firms are experiencing performance difficulties (Johnson et al.,
1993). When performance is good, directors may not feel compelled to encourage risk-taking
behavior.
Our study found that, under certain circumstances, corporate executives may be sensitive
to the presence of directors and shareholders when making important strategic decisions concerning entry into risky new markets. This study is only a first step in attempting to under-
348
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
stand the complex processes involved in evaluating and selecting new markets and determining the role that governance mechanisms play in this strategic decision. For example, this
study focused on the entry decisions of large U.S. based multinational companies into transition economies. The agency theory perspective was found to be relevant to analyze this population. However, researchers have noted that agency theory may not be generalizable to
other populations of firms from different cultures. For example, Sharp and Salter (1997)
found that agency theory has very weak explanatory power in collectivist countries including
some Asian nations. Additionally, Antal-Mokos (1998) suggests that the agency theory perspective may have shortcomings in explaining the privatization process in transition economies. Future research needs to devote more attention to these and other complex issues involved in arriving at decisions related to international expansion.
6. Conclusion
Our study represents an initial attempt at investigating the role of the corporate governance process in international investment decisions. We found support for our contention
that the composition of the board of directors and level of institutional ownership may have
an influence on the decision to invest in transition economies under certain circumstances.
However, this support was not uniform across all variables in our study. The results of this
study may hold some implications for business practitioners. Our findings may indicate that
corporate directors and institutional investors show some concern about the international investment decisions of their firms, at least when firms are performing poorly. Thus, corporate
managers should be prepared to work with these stakeholders in order to gain support for
these important international investment decisions. Future research should be conducted to
gain a better understanding of the role of governance agents in these important internationalization decisions.
Acknowledgments
The authors gratefully acknowledge the helpful comments and suggestions of three anonymous reviewers.
References
Aldrich, J.H., Nelson, F.D., 1984. Linear probability, logit, and probit models. Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA.
Andrews, K.R., 1971. The concept of corporate strategy. Irwin, Homewood, IL.
Antal-Mokos, Z., 1998. Privatisation, politics and economic performance in Hungary. Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK.
Bergson, A., 1989. Planning and performance in socialist economies. Unwin Hyman, Inc., Boston.
Blanchard, O.J., Dornbusch, R., Krugman, P., Layard, R., Summers, L., 1991. Reform in Eastern Europe. The
MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Boeker, W., Goodstein, J., 1991. Organizational performance and adaptation: effects of environment and performance on changes in board composition. Acad Manage J 34, 805–826.
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
349
Brouthers, K.D., Bamossy, G.J., 1997. The role of key stakeholders in international joint venture negotiations:
case studies from Eastern Europe. J Int Business Stud 28 (2), 285–308.
Caves, R.E., 1996. Multinational enterprise and economic analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Child, J., Czeglédy, A.P., 1996. Managerial learning in the transformation of Eastern Europe: some key issues.
Organ Stud 17 (2), 167–179.
Child, J., Kieser, J., 1981. Development of organizations over time. In: Nystrom, P., Starbuck, W. (Eds.), Handbook of organizational design. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Coffee, J.C., 1991. Liquidity versus control: the institutional investor as corporate monitor. Columbia Law Rev 91
(6), 1277–1368.
Collins, J. M., 1990. A market performance comparison of U.S. firms active in domestic, developed and developing countries. J Int Business Stud 2, 271–287.
Collins, S.M., Rodrik, D., 1991. Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union in the world economy. Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.
Cox, J.D., 1993. The ALI, institutionalizaton, and disclosure: the quest for the outside director’s spine. George
Washington Law Rev 61, 1233–1273.
Dalton, D.R., Kesner, I.F., 1985. Organizational performance as an antecedent of inside/outside chief executive
succession: an empirical assessment. Acad Manage J 28, 749–762.
De Castro, J.O., Uhlenbruck, K., 1997. Characteristics of privatization: evidence from developed, less-developed,
and former communist countries. J Int Business Stud 28 (1), 123–143.
DeMaris, A., 1992. Logit modeling: practical applications. Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA.
Demb, A., Chouet., D., Lossius, T., Neubauer, F., 1989. Defining the role of the board. Long Range Planning 22, 61–68.
Dunning, J.H., 1988. Explaining international production. Unwin Hyman, London.
Dunning, J.H., 1993. Multinational enterprises and the global economy. Addison-Wesley, Wokingham, England.
Dutton, J., Duncan, R., 1987. The creation of momentum for change through the process of strategic issue diagnosis. Strategic Manage J 8, 279–295.
Eisenhardt, K.M., 1989. Agency theory: An assessment and review, Acad Manage Rev 14 (1), 57–74.
Fama, E.F., 1980. Agency problems and the theory of the firm. J Political Econ 26, 288–307.
Fama, E.F., Jensen, M.C., 1983. Separation of ownership and control. J Law Econ 26, 301–343.
Fiegenbaum, A., Thomas, H., 1988. Attitudes toward risk and the risk-return paradox: prospect theory explanations. Acad Manage J 31, 85–106.
Fladmoe-Lindquist, K., Jacque, L.L., 1995. Control modes in international service operations: the propensity to
franchise. Manage Sci 41 (7), 1238–1249.
Froot, K.A., 1994. Foreign direct investment in Eastern Europe: some economic considerations. In: Blanchard, O.J.,
Froot, K.A., Sachs, J.D. (Eds.), The transition in Eastern Europe. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Geringer, J.M., Beamish, P.W., daCosta, R.C., 1989. Diversification strategy and internationalization: implications for MNE performance. Strategic Manage J 10, 109–119.
Gomulka, S., 1986. Growth, innovation and reform in Eastern Europe. Wheatsheaf Books Ltd, Brighton, UK.
Grant, R.M., 1987. Multinationality and performance among British manufacturing companies. J Int Business
Stud 18, 79–86.
Haberman, S.J., 1982. Analysis of dispersion of multinomial responses. J Am Stat Assoc 77, 568–580.
Hennart, J.F., 1982. A theory of multinational enterprise. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, MI.
Hitt, M.A., Hoskisson, R.E., Kim, H., 1997. International diversification: effects on innovation and firm performance in product-diversified firms. Acad Manage J 40, 767–798.
Hughes, J., Longue, D., Sweeney, R., 1975. Corporate international diversification and market assigned measures
of risk and diversification. J Financial Quant Analysis (November), 627–637.
Jensen, M.C., Meckling, W., 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. J Financial Econ 11, 305–360.
Johnson, L., Millon, D., 1993. Corporate takeovers and corporate law: who’s in control? George Washington Law
Rev 61, 1177–1211.
Johnson, R.A., Hoskisson, R.E., Hitt, M.A., 1993. Board of director involvement in restructuring: the effects of
board versus managerial controls and characteristics. Strategic Manage J 14, 33–50.
350
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
Kim, W.C., Hwang, P., Burgers, W.P., 1993. Multinationals’ diversification and the risk-return trade-off. Strategic Manage J 14, 275–286.
Kochhar, R., David, P., 1996. Institutional investors and firm innovation, a test of competing hypotheses. Strategic
Manage J 17, 73–84.
Kornai, J., 1990. The road to a free economy. W.W. Norton and Company, New York.
Kornai, J., 1992. The socialist system. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Lavigne, M., 1995. The economics of transition. St. Martin’s Press, New York.
Liao, T.F., 1994. Interpreting probability models: logit, probit, and other genaralized linear models. Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA.
Loree, D.W., Guisinger, S.E., 1995. Policy and non-policy determinants of U.S. equity foreign direct investment.
J Int Business Stud 26 (2), 281–299.
Lorsch, J.W., MacIver, E., 1989. Pawns or potentates: the reality of America’s corporate boards. Harvard Business School Press, Boston.
Lyles, M.A., Salk, J.E., 1996. Knowledge acquisition from foreign parents in international joint ventures: an empirical examination in the Hungarian context. J Int Business Stud 27 (5), 877–903.
Maddala, G.S., 1983. Limited dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK.
Marer, P., 1993. Economic transformation in Central and Eastern Europe. In: Islam, S., Mandelbaum, M. (Eds.),
Making markets: economic transformation in Eastern Europe and the post-Soviet states. Council on Foreign
Relations Press, New York.
McKiernan, P., 1992. Strategies of growth: maturity, recovery, and internationalization. Routhledge, London.
Michel, A., Shaked, I., 1986. Multinational corporations versus domestic corporations financial performance and
characteristics. J Int Business Stud 17 (1), 89–106.
Mirus, R., Yeung, B., 1986. Economic incentives for countertrade. J Int Business Stud 17 (3), 27–39.
Mitchell, W., Shaver, M., Yeung, B., 1992. Getting there in a global industry: impacts on performance of changing international presence. Strategic Manage J 13, 410–432.
Montias, J.M., 1992. On firms, hierarchies, and economic reforms. In: Kovács, J.M., Tardos, M. (Eds.), Reform
and transformation in Eastern Europe. Routledge, London.
Norusis, M.J., 1990. SPSS advanced statistics user guide. SPSS Inc., Chicago.
Olson, M., 1992. The hidden path to successful economy. In: Clague, C., Rausser, G.C. (Eds.), The emergence of
market economies in Eastern Europe. Blackwell Publishers, Cambridge, MA.
Oviatt, B., 1988. Agency and transaction cost perspectives on the manager-shareholder relationship: incentives for
congruent interests. Acad Manage Rev 13, 214–225.
Patterson, P.G., Cicic, M., Shoham, A., 1997. A temporal sequence model of satisfaction and export intentions of
service firms. J Global Marketing 10 (4), 23–43.
Pearce, J.A., Zahra, S.A., 1992. Board composition from a strategic contingency perspective. J Manage Studies
29, 411–438.
Portes, R., 1993. From central planning to a market economy. In: Islam, S., Mandelbaum, M., (Eds.), Making markets: economic transformation in Eastern Europe and the post-Soviet states. Council on Foreign Relations
Press, New York.
Reuer, J.J., Miller, K.D., 1997. Agency costs and the performance implications of international joint venture internationalization. Strategic Manage J 18, 425–438.
Root, F.R., Ahmed, A.A., 1978. The influence of policy instruments on manufacturing direct foreign investment
in developing countries. J Int Business Stud 9 (3), 81–93.
Roth, K., O’Donnell, S., 1996. Foreign subsidiary compensation strategy: an agency theory perspective. Acad
Manage J 39, 678–703.
Rugman, A.M., 1981. Inside the multinationals: the economics of internal markets. Columbia University Press,
New York.
Sabi, M., 1988. An application of the theory of foreign direct investment to multinational banking in LDCs. J Int
Business Stud 19 (3), 433–447.
Sharp, D.J., Salter, S.B., 1997. Project escalation and sunk costs: a test of the international generalizability of
agency and prospect theories. J Int Business Studies 28 (1), 101–121.
L. Tihanyi, A.E. Ellstrand/Journal of International Management 4 (1998) 337–351
351
Singh, J., 1986. Performance, slack, and risk taking in organizational decision making. Acad Manage J 29, 562–
585.
Staw, B.M., Sandelands, L.E., Dutton, J.E., 1981. Threat-rigidity effects in organizational behavior: a multi-level
analysis. Administrative Sci Q 26, 501–524.
Stevens, J., 1992. Applied multivariate statistics for the social sciences (2nd edition). Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Hillsdale, NJ.
Tansey, R., White, M., Long, R.G., Smith, M., 1996. A comparison of loglinear modeling and logistic regression
in management research. J Manage 22 (2), 339–358.
Welfens, P.J., 1992. Foreign investment in the East European transition. Manage Int Rev 32 (3), 199–218.
Whetten, D. 1987. Organizational growth and decline processes. In: Coleman, J. (Ed.), Annual review of sociology, 13. Annual Reviews, Palo Alto, CA.
Zahra, S.A., Pearce, J.A., 1989. Board of directors and corporate financial performance: A review and integrative
model. J Manage 15, 291–334.
Appendix
Table A1
Logistic regression results
Constant
Institutional investors
Prior performance
Prior performance* board structure1
Model chi-square
Correct classification ϭ 78.2%
b
SE
Wald
p
Ϫ0.185
Ϫ0.915
0.743
Ϫ0.337
8.324
0.892
0.460
0.385
0.204
df ϭ 3
0.043
3.956
3.736
2.723
0.836
0.047
0.053
0.099
0.040
n ϭ 133.
The interaction of prior performance and board structure has been recoded into a separate variable for this analysis.
1